Реферат на тему Auditor Liability Essay Research Paper Auditor LiabilityThroughout
Работа добавлена на сайт bukvasha.net: 2015-06-16Поможем написать учебную работу
Если у вас возникли сложности с курсовой, контрольной, дипломной, рефератом, отчетом по практике, научно-исследовательской и любой другой работой - мы готовы помочь.
Auditor Liability Essay, Research Paper
Auditor Liability
Throughout the Eighties and into the Nineties the question of liability has become more prevalent in the practice of public accounting. Recently, the AICPA has been lobbying for liability reform in cases involving negligence or malpractice by public accountants. Opposition to this lobbying has come from consumer advocacy organizations, trial lawyers’ associations, and state public interest groups to name a few. (Bolinger p. 53) The key to success for the AICPA, according to Gary M. Bolinger is creating an image as a, “profession performing high-quality services but faced with excessive liability burdens that harm the public interest.” (Bolinger p.56)
One should not be concerned, however, in the pending political outcome, but in weighing the evidence argued by both sides and developing a sound reasonable basis. Therefore, the remainder of this document shall concern itself with comparing the prevalent arguments of both sides against one another and drawing a conclusion based on the evidence.
Opponents of liability reform rely heavily on an idealistic constitutional argument as well as an economic argument to foster their point. The main components of their argument are as follows: Limiting recovery of loss has a detrimental effect on those which are harmed by alleged negligence. The cost of liability is reasonable when compared to total revenues, and in light of a CPA’s public responsibility. Indemnity insurance spreads risk in the aggregate therefore removing the element of risk at the firm level. The threat of litigation provides public accountants with a deterrent against negligent work. Finally, the results of lawsuits cause the profession itself to implement new standards. (Bolinger p.54)
The AICPA and its supporters have developed their argument based on continued liability’s likely effect on the profession as well as an economic argument. The arguments in favor of liability reform include the effect of continued liability on the availability of CPA services. The likelihood of fee increases resulting from liability risk. The threat of the inability of public accounting to obtain and retain qualified individuals. (Bolinger p.56) Finally, the complexities involved in the audit engagement and the subjective decision making process versus the ability of a given jury to understand and levy a fair decision in such cases. After examining the arguments of both sides one will see that litigation in its current form is a hindrance to the accounting profession as well as society, and the benefits provided by litigation are attainable through enforcement of professional standards.
The first of the opponents arguments finds it’s basis from idealistic Constitutional principal. The notion that those which have been wronged, either directly or indirectly, deserve compensation for their estimated loss is one which first found favor in the case of Thomas v. Winchester in 1942. (Minnis p.4) In this case, for the first time a third party received compensation. (Minnis p.4) The precedent set by this case is the notion of duty owed to a third party– if it ascertains that a duty is owed then a third party has a right to seek compensation. The case which most directly affected auditors is a case filed in the UK, Hedley Byrne and Co Ltd v Heller and Partners Ltd (1964). (Minnis p.9) This case ultimately developed a situation where a bank passed to its client a certificate of credit-worthiness on a potential client. The business which was deemed credit-worthy ultimately failed, and claim resulted by the third party against the bank issuing the certificate.!
(Minnis p.9) The finding in the
The notion that all parties remotely affected by a given action (or lack thereof) deserve compensation for their loss is one which is embraced by the legal community– and rightfully so, after all a drastic reduction in the number of claims filed would result otherwise. The argument made in its favor is that all those harmed by negligent activity deserve compensation. Idealistically this is true, and theoretically anyone who makes a decision based entirely on the results of an auditor’s report, and suffers a loss due to negligence in preparation by the auditor, deserves compensation. Realistically, however, this is not usually the case. With the exception of banks, whom are approached by businesses for the possibility of tendering a loan, and therefore do not initiate contact; all other investors would only take the time to review the financial statements of a given company if another mitigating force attracted them. Therefore, it is reasonably asserted, that significa!
nt third parties, such as banks a
A second argument against liability reform is that the cost of malpractice suits are reasonable in comparison with the revenues and level of public responsibility delegated to CPA firms. An argument against this is made twofold. First, the total number of claims is not reasonable, but rather, astronomical. “According to a recent industry estimate, the accounting profession as a whole is facing 4,000 lawsuits and $30 billion in potential claims pending against it.” (Clolery p.42) Recent trends indicate the total value of claims are continually increasing, one has to ask at what point will the value of claims become unreasonable? As claims continue to increase the demand for indemnity insurance, which is cyclical in nature, will increase also causing insurance expense to continually rise.
This brings about the second argument which is indemnity insurance itself. Indemnity insurance is a very specialized area of insurance and most insurers are unwilling to underwrite it. (Minnis p.58) When discussing the cost of assuming liability for accounting firms, one must take into consideration that as claims increase and insurance companies begin assuming losses as a result of indemnity claims, the willingness of firms to underwrite indemnity insurance decreases substantially; and those who do underwrite it will demand a much higher premium resulting from the decreasing supply and to compensate for losses generated previously. (Layton-Cook p.109) In the long term, the argument that revenues substantiate the cost of claims is no longer justifiable on a ratio basis. To illustrate, firm XYZ has insurance costs x and fees y. Over time insurance costs increase by z and consequently fees increase by z. The resulting ratio is x+z/y+z rather than x/y.
The opposition’s third argument is insurance spreads the risk over the aggregate. Theoretically, this is true– firms pass insurance costs to clients who in turn pass additional overhead costs to consumers. Additionally, all firms carry insurance therefore causing each firm to bear the brunt of liability risk. Realistically speaking, however, a point is reached where the inflationary implications of insurance is greater than the market is willing to accept creating a situation where clients are no longer willing to accept the additional costs imposed by firms to compensate insurance expense leaving the firms as bearers of the cost of liability risk. Also, when taking into consideration the fact that a firm’s cost of indemnity insurance is at least partially dependent on prior claims against the firm, a situation will arise when firms are unwilling to accept engagements which present risk, leaving the market with a certain number of businesses which firms are not willing!
to represent.
The final two arguments of the opposition are sufficiently related to combine into one discussion. These are: the threat of litigation acts as a deterrent against negligence, and malpractice suits lead to professional reform. The first of these arguments is clearly true, litigation threat does indeed act as a deterrent against negligence. Currently, the primary means of punishing negligent acts is through litigation; therefore, one can reasonably assume the threat of lawsuit causes firms to exhibit a greater level of care when completing an engagement. If, however, standard violations are investigated and handled properly by the profession this means is also accomplishable.
Finally, the opposition asserts litigation promotes reform. Again, the same argument as before is appliable– if the profession accepts the responsibility of investigating possible claims of malpractice and negligence, and acts in areas where new standards are necessary the same result is achievable.
The arguments the AICPA have developed in favor of liability reform begin with the effect of litigation on the availability of accounting services. As claims increase firms are forced to selectively choose their client base in an effort to limit their liability risk. This phenomena is briefly covered in the section on indemnity insurance. In an article entitled “How To Get Sued” Patrick Romano, CMA lists ten surefire ways to ensure a lawsuit. His rule five states, “Choose clients whose principals are not honest, and take no extra precautions” (Romano p.58) This illustrates a continuing trend which is prevalent in the profession, which is avoid liability risk by better screening prospective clients. This seems reasonable, except for the fact that all SEC corporations require audits, and audits are required in other situations as well. In the end, someone must accept the audit engagement; and with the ever looming threat of lawsuit a point is reached when there are no !
willing takers. When this situat
completeness. Additionally, he asserts staff qualifications as a major point of emphasis in litigation. (Clolery p.44) The result is firms must incur extra expenses in order to, not only adhere to the principals of GAAS; but also to provide the appearance of adhering to GAAS.
This brings up another key point in the liability reform issue, which is the likelihood of fee increases. Fee increases as a result of malpractice are incurred in three areas: the increase resulting from insurance expense, the increase resulting from the costs of performing the engagement, and increases resulting from litigation expense. The first two issues are covered previously. The area of insurance expense is discussed in the section covering indemnity insurance, while the cost of the engagement is illustrated in the most recent section. Additionally, the cost of litigation services are also absorbed in engagement fees.
A third area used in the AICPA’s argument is that of obtaining and retaining quality professionals. The basis for this argument is that well educated intelligent persons, ones which public accounting seeks to attract into the profession, are less likely to pursue a career in public accounting if high levels of liability risk exist. Furthermore, those who do enter public accounting are more likely to leave the profession due to liability risk. This argument has merit inasmuch as pointing out the professions dedication to employ only qualified individuals; however the effect it will have on those choosing to enter the profession is difficult to prove. One may ascertain the rationale behind leaving a profession where the pressures of liability exist, but public accounting will never have difficulty recruiting young professionals.
Finally, an area not addressed by the AICPA but which deserves consideration nevertheless, is that of the complexities and subjectiveness of auditing versus the ability of jurors to issue an educated decision. The justice system relies on the services of jurors to levy decisions; however, in highly technical areas the ability of jurors is suspect. In malpractice cases the verdict often hinges on compliance with GAAS. (Buckless p.164)
A study was conducted concerning juror decisions based on a firm’s compliance with GAAS by Frank A. Buckless and Robert L. Peace of the North Carolina State University. They conducted a factorial experiment using 2×2 format. The four possibilities are as follows: instructions indicating compliance with GAAS and such compliance is the only considerable factor, compliance with GAAS and all factors are considered, compliance with government standards and only compliance is considerable, and compliance with government standards with all factors being considered. (Buckless p.169) The study concluded, “that jurors attached greater credibility to auditing standards established by the federal government than to those established by the auditing profession.” (Buckless p.173) In a subsequent article the point is raised that when discussing the issue of government versus professional standards, one area included a government witness while the other a witness from the profession, b!
ut not a cross sample of both; th
In regression analysis of the same sample, education is found significant with those more educated being more likely to find in favor of the auditor. (Buckless p.172) This creates significant implications regarding a jury’s ability to reach a fair verdict in cases as technical and subjective as accounting malpractice cases.
The above argument shows major points used by both sides in the ongoing fight involving liability reform in public accounting. Additionally it suggests that the profession itself need bear the burden of deterrence, enforcement, and investigation whereby eliminating the existing systems only strength. If the AICPA in cooperation with state boards becomes more willing to accept the role as investigator and punisher, then the economics of the argument suggest that liability reform is in order.
32a