Реферат на тему UnH1d Essay Research Paper The soaring volume
Работа добавлена на сайт bukvasha.net: 2015-06-18Поможем написать учебную работу
Если у вас возникли сложности с курсовой, контрольной, дипломной, рефератом, отчетом по практике, научно-исследовательской и любой другой работой - мы готовы помочь.
Untitled Essay, Research Paper
The soaring volume of international finance and increased interdependence
in
recent decades has increased concerns about volatility and threats of a financial
crisis.
This has led many to investigate and analyze the origins, transmission, effects
and policies
aimed to impede financial instability. This paper argues that financial
liberalization and
speculation are the most reflective explanations for instability in financial
markets and that
financial instability is likely to be transmitted globally with far reaching
implications on real
sector performance. I conclude the paper with the argument that a global
transaction tax
would be the most effective policy to curb financial instability and that
other proposed
policies, such as target zones and the creation of a supranational institution,
are either
unfeasible or unattainable.
INSTABILITY IN FINANCIAL MARKETS
In this section I examine four interpretations of how
financial instability arises.
The first interpretation deals with speculation and the subsequent
“bandwagoning” in
financial markets. The second is a political interpretation dealing with
the declining status
of a hegemonic anchor of the financial system. The question of whether regulation
causes
or mitigates financial instability is raised by the third interpretation;
while the fourth view
deals with the “trigger point” phenomena.
To fully comprehend these interpretations we must first
understand and
differentiate between a “currency” and “contagion” crisis.
A currency crisis refers to a
situation is which a loss of confidence in a country’s currency provokes
capital flight.
Conversely, a contagion crisis refers to a loss of confidence in the assets
denominated in a
particular currency and the subsequent global transmission of this shock.
One of the more paramount readings of financial instability
pertains to speculation.
Speculation is exhibited in a situation where a government monetary or fiscal
policy (or
action) leads investors to believe that the currency of that particular nation
will either
appreciate or depreciate in terms relative to those of other countries. Closely
associated
with these speculative attacks is what is coined the “bandwagon”
effect. Say for
example, that a country’s central bank decides to undertake an expansionary
monetary
policy. A neoclassical interpretation tells us that this will lower the domestic
interest
rates, thus lowering the rate of return in the foreign exchange market and
bringing about a
currency depreciation. As investors foresee this happening they will likely
pull out before
the perceived depreciation. “Efforts to get out would accelerate the
loss of reserves,
provoking an earlier collapse, speculators would therefore try to get out
still earlier, and
so on” (Krugman, 1991:93). This “herding” or
“bandwagon” effect naturally cause wild
swings in exchange rates and volatility in markets.
Another argument for the evolution of financial market
instability is closely related
to hegemonic stability theory. This political explanation predicts a circumstance
(i.e. a
decline of a hegemon’s status) in which a loss of confidence in a particular
countries
currency may lead to capital flight away from that currency. This flight
in turn not only
depreciates the currency of the former hegemon but more importantly undermines
its role
as the international financial anchor and is said to ultimately lead to
instability.
The trigger point phenomena may also be used as an instrument
to explain financial
instability. Similar to the speculative cycles described above, this refers
to a situation
where a group of investors commits to buy or sell a currency when that currency
reaches a
certain price level. If that particular currency were to rise or fall to
that specified level,
whether by real or speculative reasons, the precommited investors buy or
sell that
currency or assets. This results in a cascade effect that, like speculative
cycles, increases
or decreases the value of the currency to remarkably higher or lower levels.
Country after country has deregulated its financial markets
and institutions. The
neoclassical interpretation asserts that regulation is thought to create
incentives for risk
taking and hence instability. It is said to bring about what are called
“moral hazards.”
Proponents of deregulation argue that when people are insured, they are more
apt to take
greater risks with their investments in financial markets. The riskier the
investment
activity, the more volatile the markets tend to be.
A closer look suggests that perhaps only two of these
explanations are valid when
thinking about the origins of financial instability. The trigger point
explanation seems to
be a misreading of the origins of instability. It is unlikely that a large
number of investors
would have the incentive or operational ability in order to simultaneously
coordinate the
buying or selling of a currency or assets denominated in that currency. If
even there is
such unlikely coordination, the “existence of even a very large group
of investors with
trigger points need not create a crisis if other investors know they are
there” (Krugman,
1991:96).
The theory of hegemonic stability also overlooks a number
of factors that can
provide useful insights in explaining the emergence of financial instability.
Historical
precedence supports this assertion. For instance, Britains role as international
economic
manager was very minor in the stability experienced under the gold standard.
The success
of the standard can be attributed to endogenous factors such as the self
adjusting market
mechanism and the informal discipline maintained by its rules. The
destabilization of the
gold standard can be attributed to the extreme domestic economic and financial
pressures
brought on nation states by World War I, and not solely on the industrial
and economic
demise of Britain.
A valid explanation for the origins of financial instability
are the speculative attacks
brought on by investors. Although similar in function to trigger points,
these speculative
cycles cannot be mitigated simply by pure recognition. Rather than acting
on the value of
the currency itself, speculators act on occurrences or policies that will
alter the value of
the currency. Instability arises from the fact that these speculative cycles
induce capital
flight and therefore a change in the value of that particular currency, whether
or not the
decisions of these investors are based on market “fundamentals.”
Futures, options, swaps
and other financial instruments “have given investors and speculators
an unheard of
capacity to leverage financial markets. The greater the leverage, the greater
the
instability” (McCallum, 1995:12).
If we examine the deregulatory process closely, it becomes
clear that there is a
perverse relationship between deregulation and financial stability. Say for
example,
investors suffer from a profit squeeze. This causes the investors to lobby
politicians for
deregulation. The resulting wave of deregulation fosters instability and
wide swings in
exchange rates which in turn cause loan defaults and subsequent banking crisis.
The
resulting financial instability thus begs calls regulation, likely placing
the investors in the
original position with an unsolved problem. We can see that the dialectic
of the regulatory
process undermines anticipated stability and will eventually lead to financial
instability and
collapse. In this environment, there arises calls for new forms of financial
regulation.
These policies and proposals are of critical importance and will therefore
be discussed
later in the paper.
THE TRANSMISSION AND EFFECTS OF FINANCIAL INSTABILITY
There are three contending albeit interrelated views on
how financial instability
may be transmitted globally. These include equity markets, multiplier effects
and
monetary reverberations.
Say for example, a movement of stock prices generates
a recession in one country.
This is turn leads to a reduce in imports from abroad. The lower aggregate
demand for
foreign imports will generate a contraction in other country’s output
markets. The
resulting contraction in the foreign countries will then induce a contraction
in the
originating country. As seen, the multiplier effect begins to take place
that in turn leads
to a global recession.
If an asset crash leads to a monetary crises, the money
crisis could be transmitted
worldwide. The Mundell-Flemming model assumes that under a fixed exchange
rate
system, such as that under the gold standard, a worldwide monetary contraction
will result
from a contraction in any one particular country because “a monetary
contraction in one
country, which raises interest rates in that country, must be matched by
an equal rise in
rates elsewhere” (Krugman, 1991:103). However, under a flexible exchange
rate system,
such as the one in operation today, the model predicts that monetary shocks
will be
transmitted perversely, that is, a monetary contraction in one country will
produce
expansion elsewhere. Herring and Litan (1995) advance this argument by concluding
that
the transmission of crisis creates a “systemic risk.” This view
states that continuous
losses in financial markets has adverse effects on the real economy because
“significant
losses can occur if there is a significant disruption in the payments system
or the
mechanism through which transactions for goods, services, and assets are
cleared”
(Herring and Litan, 1995:51) .
While it may be accepted that financial crises can be
transmitted globally, there is
debate on its ramifications on the real sector of the economy. Krugman (1991:97)
states
that a currency depreciation “will produce an improvement in competitiveness
that will
increase net exports and thus have an expansionary effect on the domestic
economy.” He
also asserts that policy responses may help to curb real sectors effects.
When currencies
depreciate, government officials and central bankers raise interest rates
to discourage
capital flight. The recessionary effects of tight monetary and fiscal policies,
it is argued,
dilute the inflationary repercussions of the currency crisis. Citing historical
evidence of the
US stock market crash, Kapstein (1996:6) goes so far as to say that the real
economy is
“shockproof” from transmission of financial instability and even
in the face of financial
crisis “continues to function normally.”
The assumption that swings in financial markets do not
influence real sector
performance is inattentive to many factors. Advocates of this view use what
is percieved
as relatively small repercussions felt worldwide after the US stock market
crash in 1929
where “in general the slump was mild” (Krugman 1991:91). The empirical
data of the
slump underscores this argument. Between December 1929 and December 1932,
for
example, Germany experienced a 30.% percent stock market decline, France
38.5 percent
and Canada 37.5% (Kindleberger, 1973). If we keep in mind that the percentage
swing in
the US stock during that same period was 37.3 percent, we see that the slump
was only
slightly “milder” but by no means “mild.” The real sector
ramifications were just as
remarkable. Germany saw a 58 percent decline in industrial production, France
74 percent
and Canada 68 percent, all comparably higher declines than in the United
States (Yeager,
1976).
It is obvious that financial crises do have global spillover
effects and consequences
on real sector performance. However, recognition of these adverse effects
does not solve
the problem. In the next section I present contending policies and proposals
designed to
curb international financial instability and its repugnant ramifications.
CONTENDING VIEWS AND POLICY PROPOSALS
Three main policies have been introduced to curb international
financial instability.
A global transaction tax, which is a tax on short term financial investments,
a target zone
approach, where nations exchange rates would be allowed to fluctuate within
a specific
band and a supranational or regional institution aimed at coordinating global
financial
reform.
Proposed by economists and Nobel Laureate James Tobin
in 1978, a global
transaction tax (STT) would act to “throw some sand in the well greased
wheels of the
global financial markets.” The STT is predicted to slow the short term
financial
excursions into other currencies, yet at the same time it would have a lighter
impact on
trade and long-term investments with higher percentage yields. Speculators,
now carrying
the burden of a tax woul therefore have less “leverage” with which
to exploit exchange
volatility while long-term investment would be encouraged. Another benefit
of the tax is
that it would reduce wasted financial resources and increase government
revenues.
While proponents of the STT say the policy will reduce
wasted financial resources,
others argue that there would be an adjustment problem because of the fact
that “goods
and the price of labor moved in response to international price signals much
more
sluggishly than fluid funds, and prices in goods and labor markets moved
more sluggishly
than prices of financial assets.”(McCallum, 1995:16) Others attack the
view that excess
volatility would be eliminated because “deciding whether volatility
is excessive is
complicated by difficulty of determining the fundamental value of a
security” (Hakkio,
1994:22). Opponents of the tax argue that it could be avoided by product
substitution and
regulatory arbitrage and that the government revenue created would be
overestimated
because “the tax base would decline as security prices and the volume
of trading decline”
(Hakkio 1994: 26).
Advocates of the “efficient market hypothesis”
argue that if financial markets are
allowed to freely operate, there will be a revaluation of asset values that
will produce the
most accurate price signals on which to base long-term resource allocations.
They say that
a STT would be detrimental to less developed countries so reliant on short
term
investment.
Another highly noted policy aimed at curbing international
financial instability is
the adoption of a targeted exchange rate system. A sort of “hybrid”
regime, target zones
allows currencies to fluctuate within predetermined and set bands, thus allowing
a “float”
but at the same time keeping a “fix.” Since “the main sources
of conflict have been the
unpredictability of exchange rates” (Frenkel, 1990:318) a target zone
approach would in
theory alleviate this unpredictability, while keeping the appealing attributes
of a floating
system. Seen to be the optimal answer for coordinated exchange rate
stabilization, “target
zones would involve the determination of an international consensus regarding
an
appropriate and globally feasible range around which currency values could
fluctuate”
(Grabel, 1993:77).
The adoption of a target zone system would not be universally
beneficial.
Naturally, the size, status and sector of the economy play an important role
in its
desirability. Government officials and central bankers will likely oppose
the adoption of a
targeted exchange rate due to the fact that it would hurt their ability to
change the value of
their currency in the face of high capital mobility. With a targeted exchange
rate, it is
argued that there is limited room for fluctuation which infringes on the
effectiveness of
domestic policies. On the other hand, the fixity of the target zone would
in theory stabilize
purchasing power of wage earners in both developed and less developed.
The overriding problem of the adoption of a target zone
regime is that there is no
clear way in which target zones could be calculated. If they were to be
calculated what
would be the ramifications if a country was to fluctuate out of the specific
bands? Would
the target zones be global or regional? If global, how could the less developed
countries
be able to stay in the same bands as the developed countries? If a target
zone was adopted,
what is to say the maldistribution of wealth would not remain idle? There
seems to be
little, if any, evidence that a fixed, stabilized exchange rate leads to
higher or lower interest
rates. If the value of a currency is not able to adapt to high tendencies
of capital mobility,
then it is only rational to say that the developed countries would continue
to sap the
wealth of less developed countries.
The last major policy aimed at quelling financial instability
is the creation of a
supranational institution aimed at coordinating financial reform and adopting
a system of
“regulatory supervision.” Processing along the lines of a Bretton
Woods architecture, this
would in a sense institutionalize the role of a hegemon with “a creation
of a common
currency for all of the industrial democracies” and “a joint Bank
of Issue to determine
monetary [and financial] policies” (Cooper, 1984:166). This policy proposal
endorses the
adoption of an global financial institution managing the operation of
coordinated
supervision.
Experience shows us that coordinated supervision is not
possible in international
financial markets. For instance, the Basel Concordant was never able to
reach
organizational level to properly respond to a crisis. Additionally, “the
BCCI affair
demonstrated the limitations of international bank supervision when confronted
by
unscrupulous operators intent on exploiting the gaps in national bank supervisory
systems”
(Herring and Litan, 1995:105).
Proponents of re-creating a Bretton Woods-type system
are unaware of the lessons
to be learned from that period. The theoretical brethren of hegemonic stability
advocates,
proponents of this policy seek too place “the direction of world monetary
policy in the
hands of a single country” or institution that would have “great
influence over the
economic destiny of others” (Williamson, 1977:37). As seen under the
Bretton Woods
system the “destiny” of others was in the hands of a country that
was unable to maintain
stability. It is yet to be demonstrated how an institutional framework would
sidestep the
same faultlines and management problems experienced by the United States
under the
Bretton Woods regime.
The organizational barriers to creating such cooperation
and coordination would
be insurmountable. Secondly, whose view would most likely be presented in
the
supranational forum? Experience in international organizations shows us that
it will
probably be the powerful, industrialized nations. The voice and needs of
the less
developed countries is likely to be marginalized and situations such as the
Latin American
debt crisis would continue to occur.
When looking at the progress of the European Monetary
Union we see that the
completion of a single market is far too radical for today’s international
financial climate.
Just as “the costs of qualifying for the EMU has become too high”
it becomes “unrealistic
to hope that the major industrial countries can make comparable strides toward
political
[much less financial] unification in our lifetime” (Eichengreen and
Tobin, 1995:170).
Ideally, the best policy for stemming financial instability
and spillover effects would
be one that extinguishes the problem at its roots. If deregulation in itself
causes instability
in financial markets, then regulation would be appealing. “Even when
the benefits of
financial deregulation are apparent, there is a role for regulatory policy”
that would “leave
the world economy less vulnerable to financial collapse” (Eichengreen
and Portes,
1987:51). . If we also hold true the conclusion that the best explanation
for financial
instability is speculation, then a global securities transaction tax such
as the one proposed
by Tobin would be optimal. The discouragement of short term speculative
excursions and
the endorsement of long-term investment will eliminate the problem of volatility
based on
speculative attacks that so often stray from market “fundamentals.”
Critics are quite
correct when they argue that the tax could induce financial arbitrage and
substitution.
However this problem would be solved as long as the tax was globally adopted.
Secondly, the tax would be applied to goods, services, and financial instruments
that had
few or no substitutes. The view that the creation of new government revenues
is
overestimated and that Third World countries would carry the financial burden
is nullified
when we see that “a .5 percent tax on exchange transaction would augment
government
revenues globally by as much as $300 to $400 billion per anum” and
“devoting merely
10-20 percent of that revenue to a revolving fund for long-term lending to
Third World
countries would be a healthy substitute for the hot money on which some have
become
disastrously overdependent” (McCallum, 1995:16).
The recognition and ceasing of financial instability and
its global transmission is
becoming more and more universally endorsed. To decide on a prudent and
practical
policy will prove to be a major hurdle of international financial leaders
around the world.
However, if we look closely, we will find the locus of instability in financial
markets to be
deregulation and speculative attacks. Government and central bankers can
no longer
adopt an attitude of “benign neglect” toward international financial
instability as it
becomes increasingly apparent that there are far reaching consequences on
real sectors.
We can see that there is one policy that supersedes the rest. If the world
financial system
hopes to curb these real sector ramifications of speculative attacks and
financial
liberalization, then it becomes indisputable that the STT is an idea whose
time has come.
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Richard N. Cooper, “A Monetary System for the Future” Foreign Affairs
Fall, 1984.Barry Eichengreen and Richard Portes, “The Anatomy of Financial
Crisis,” in Richard
Portes and Alexander Swoboda, Threats to International
Financial Stability,
(Cambridege University Press, 1987).Barry Eichengreen, James Tobin and Charles Wyplosz, “Two Cases for Sand
in the Whells
of International Finance” Economic Journal, 1995.Jacob Frenkel, “The International Monetary System: Should It Be
Reformed” in Philip
King, editor, International Economics and International
Economic Policy
(McGraw-Hill,1990).Ilene Grabel, “Crossing Borders: A Case for Cooperation in International
Financial
Markets,” in Gerald Epstein, Julie Graham, Jessica
Nembard (eds.), Creating a
New World Economy: Forces of Change and Plans of Action
(Temple University
Press, 1993).Charles Hakkio, “Should we Throw Sand in the Gears of Financial
Markets?” Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Review, 1994.Richard Herring and Robert Litan, Financial Regulation in the Global
Economy
(Brookings Institution, 1995).Ethan Kapstein, “Shockproof: The End of Financial Crisis” Foreign
Affairs,
January/February 1996.Charles P. Kindleberger, The World in Depression (London: Penguin 1973).Paul Krugman, “International Aspects of Financial Crises” in Martin
Feldstein, ed., The
Risk of Economic Crisis (Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 1991).John McCallum, “Managers and Unstable Financial Markets” Business
Quarterly January
1, 1995.James Tobin, “A proposal for international monetary reform” Eastern
Economic Journal
1978, volume 4.John Williamson, The Failure of World Monetary Reform 1971-1974) (NY:NYU
Press,
1977)L.B. Yeager, International Monetary Relations: Theory, History, and Policy
1976.
318