Реферат на тему Despondency Essay Research Paper DespondencyThe Great Depression
Работа добавлена на сайт bukvasha.net: 2015-06-05Поможем написать учебную работу
Если у вас возникли сложности с курсовой, контрольной, дипломной, рефератом, отчетом по практике, научно-исследовательской и любой другой работой - мы готовы помочь.
Despondency Essay, Research Paper
Despondency
The Great Depression was the worst economic slump ever in U.S. history, and one which spread to virtually all of the industrialized world. The depression began in late 1929 and lasted for about a decade. Many factors played a role in bringing about the depression; however, the main cause for the Great Depression was the combination of the greatly unequal distribution of wealth throughout the 1920’s, and the extensive stock market speculation that took place during that same decade.
The lack of distribution of wealth in the 1920’s existed on many levels. Money was distributed unequally between the rich and the middle-class, between industry and agriculture within the United States, and between the U.S. and Europe. This imbalance of wealth created an unstable economy. The stock market was kept artificially high, but eventually led to large market crashes. These market crashes, combined with the lack of distribution of wealth, caused the American economy to capsize.
The “roaring twenties” was an era when our country prospered tremendously. The nation’s total realized income rose from $74.3 billion in 1923 to $89 billion in 1929(Sobel 26). However, the rewards of the “Coolidge Prosperity” of the 1920’s were not shared evenly among all Americans. In 1929 the top 0.1% of Americans controlled 34% of all savings, while 80% of Americans had no savings at all (Fremon 16). Automotive industry entrepreneur Henry Ford is one example of the unequal distribution of wealth between the rich and the middle-class. Henry Ford reported a personal income of $14 million in the same year that the average persons income was $750 (McElvaine 295). This lack of distribution of income between the rich and the middle class grew throughout the 1920’s. A major reason for this large and growing gap between the rich and the working-class people was the increased manufacturing output throughout the 1920?s. From 1923-1929 the average output per worker increased 32% (Schraff 14). During that same period of time average wages for manufacturing jobs increased only 8% (14). As production costs fell quickly, wages rose slowly, and prices remained constant, the bulk benefit of the increased productivity went into corporate profits(14).
The federal government also contributed to the growing gap between the rich and middle-class. Calvin Coolidge’s administration favored business. An example of legislation to this purpose is the Revenue Act of 1926, which greatly reduced federal income and inheritance taxes (McElvaine 23). Andrew Mellon was the main force behind these and other tax cuts throughout the 1920’s. Because of these tax cuts a man with a million-dollar annual income had his federal taxes reduced from $600,000 to $200,000 (23). Even the Supreme Court played a role in expanding the gap between the socioeconomic classes. In the1923 case Adkins v. Children’s Hospital, the Supreme Court ruled minimum-wage legislation unconstitutional(McElvaine 30). The large and growing difference of wealth between the well-to-do and the middle-income citizens made the U.S. economy unstable.
For an economy to function properly, total demand must equal total supply. Essentially what happened in the 1920’s was that there was an oversupply of goods. It was not that the surplus products were not wanted, but rather that those who needed the products could not afford more, while the wealthy were satisfied by spending only a small portion of their income. Three quarters of the U.S. population would spend essentially all of their yearly incomes to purchase goods such as food, clothes, radios, and cars. These were the poor and middle class. Families with incomes around, or usually less than, $2,500 a year (Fremon 14). While the wealthy too purchased consumer goods, a family earning $100,000 could not be expected to eat 40 times more than a family that only earned $2,500 a year(14).
Through the imbalance, the U.S. came to rely upon two things in order for the economy to remain on an even level: credit sales, or investment from the rich. One obvious solution to the problem of the vast majority of the population not having enough money to satisfy all their needs was to let those who wanted goods buy products on credit. The concept of buying now and paying later caught on quickly. By the end of the 1920’s, 60% of cars, and 80% of radios were bought on installment credit (Farrell 26). Between 1925 and 1929 the total amount of outstanding installment credit more than doubled (26). This strategy created a non-realistic demand for products which people could not usually afford. People could no longer use their regular wages to purchase whatever items they didn’t have yet, because so much of the wages went to paying back past purchases.
The U.S. economy was also reliant upon luxury spending and investment from the rich to stay afloat during the 1920’s. The largest problem with this reliance was that luxury spending and investment were based on the wealthy’s confidence in the U.S. economy. If conditions were to take a downturn (as they did when the market crashed in the fall of 1929), this spending and investment would slow to a halt. Lastly, the search for ever greater returns on investment led to wide-spread market speculation. Lack of distribution of wealth within our nation was not limited to only socioeconomic classes, but to entire industries. In 1929 a mere 200 corporations controlled approximately half of all corporate wealth (McElvaine 201). During World War I the federal government had encouraged farmers to buy more land, to modernize their methods with the latest in farm technology, and to produce more food. This made sense during the war since Europe had to be fed too. However as soon as the war ended, the U.S. abruptly stopped its policies to help farmers. Farm and food prices tumbled (Fremon 60).
A last major instability of the American economy had to do with international wealth distribution problems. While America was prospering in the 1920’s, European nations were rebuilding themselves after the damage of war. During World War I the U.S. government lent its European allies $7 billion (Farrell 55). American foreign lending continued in the 1920’s climbing to $900 million in 1924, 90% of this money was used by the European allies to purchase U.S. goods (McElvaine 343). The nations the U.S. had lent money to (Britain, Italy, France, Belgium, Russia, Yugoslavia, Estonia, Poland, and others) were in no position to pay off the debts. The majority of their gold had been sent into the U.S. during and immediately after the war; they couldn’t send more gold without completely ruining their currencies (McElvaine 350) .
In the 1920’s the United States was trying to be the world’s banker, food producer, and manufacturer, but bought as little as possible from the rest of the world in return. This attempt to have a ?constantly favorable trade balance? could not work for long (Fremon 76). If the United States would not buy from our European countries, then there was no way for them to buy from the Americans, or even to pay interest on U.S. loans. The weakness of the international economy certainly contributed to the Great Depression. Europe was dependent upon U.S. loans to buy U.S. goods, and the U.S. needed Europe to buy these goods to do well (Fremon 82). From early 1928 to September 1929 the Dow Jones Industrial Average rose greatly (82). This sort of profit was tempting to investors. Company earnings became of little interest; as long as stock prices continued to rise huge profits could be made. Through the miracle of buying stocks on margin, one could buy stocks without the money to purchase them. Buying stocks on margin worked the same way as buying a car on credit. Investors’ craze over the plan of profits like this drove the market to extremely high levels. The exploratory boom in the stock market was based upon confidence.
In the same way, the huge market crashes of 1929 were based on fear. Prices had been drifting downward since early September, but generally people were optimistic. Speculators continued to flock to the market. Then, on Monday October 21 prices started to fall quickly (Schraff 17). Investors became fearful. Knowing that prices were falling, but not by how much, they started selling quickly. This caused the collapse to happen faster. Prices stabilized a little on Tuesday and Wednesday, but then on Black Thursday, October 24, everything fell apart again. By this time most major investors had lost confidence in the market. Once enough investors had decided the boom was over, it was over. Partial recovery was achieved on Friday and Saturday when a group of leading bankers stepped in to try to stop the crash. But then on Monday the 28th prices started dropping again. By the end of the day the market had fallen 13% (Schraff 21). The next day, Black Tuesday an unprecedented 16.4 million shares changed hands (Fremon16). This stock market crashes acted as a trigger to the already unstable U.S. economy.
Due to the lack of distribution of wealth, the economy of the 1920’s was very much dependent upon confidence. The market crashes damaged this confidence. The rich stopped spending on luxury items, and slowed investments. The middle-class and poor stopped buying things with installment credit for fear of loosing their jobs, and not being able to pay the interest. Industrial production fell by more than 9% between the market crashes in October and December 1929 (Farrell 23). As a result jobs were lost, and soon people starting failing to pay their interest payment. Thriving industries that had been connected with the automotive and radio industry started falling apart. Without a car people did not need fuel or tires; without a radio people had less need for electricity. To protect the nation’s businesses the U.S. imposed higher trade barriers, Hawley-Smoot Tariff of 1930 (McElvvaine 83). Foreigners stopped buying American products. More jobs were lost, more stores were closed, more banks went under, and more factories closed. Unemployment grew to five million in 1930, and up to thirteen million in 1932 (McElvaine 202). The country spiraled quickly into catastrophe. The Great Depression had begun.
Farrell, Jacquelin. The Great Depression. California: Lucent Books, 1996.
Fremon, David. The Great Depression. New Jersey: Enslow Publishers Inc., 1997.
McElvaine, Roberts.The Great Depression.New York: Times Books, 1984.
Schraff, Anne. The Great Depression and The New Deal. New York: Chelsea House Publishers, 1990.
Sobel, Robert. Herbert Hoover at the onset of the Great Depression. Philadelphia: J.B. Lippincott Company, 1975.