Реферат на тему Private School Vouchers Essay Research Paper Proposals
Работа добавлена на сайт bukvasha.net: 2015-06-15Поможем написать учебную работу
Если у вас возникли сложности с курсовой, контрольной, дипломной, рефератом, отчетом по практике, научно-исследовательской и любой другой работой - мы готовы помочь.
Private School Vouchers Essay, Research Paper
Proposals to use private school vouchers,
a marketplace strategy, as a mechanism by which to improve the general
quality of public education have produced a lively debate. Frequently,
that debate has degenerated into a disagreement about whether public schools
are as good as private schools or whether a given private school is better
than a certain neighborhood public school.
Other issues raised in these discussions
include the appropriate use of public funds, the role of competition in
improving public education, and the right of parents to choose a school
for their children. Although these issues are of interest, they are not
the fundamental questions which must be raised about the future of public
schools in a democracy.
Two Core Issues
In their rush to the marketplace, the
proponents of private school choice supported by public funds have chosen
to ignore two core issues. First, the advocates of private school choice
studiously avoid any discussion of the relationship between public schools
and the common or public good in a democracy. As an example, the Governor
of Wisconsin asserts that “any school that serves the public is a public
school” and should therefore receive public funds through a voucher system.
There is no recognition in this proposal of the distinct and unique purpose
of public education in serving the public good. This rhetorical sleight-of-hand
does not mean that a private school of choice becomes a public school in
purpose simply by so defining it. The claim is merely a device to divert
public funds for private purposes.
The failure to recognize that public schools
have a central responsibility in a democratic society is further evidenced
by the work of John Chubb and Terry Moe, who argue that improving the efficiency
and quality of public education will require the replacement of democratic
governance by market mechanisms.
The authors state, “The most basic cause
of ineffective performance among the nation’s public schools is their subordination
to public authority. … The school’s most fundamental problems are rooted
in the institutions of democratic control by which they are governed”.
Chubb and Moe deny the historic purposes
of public schools when they reject the idea that educational policy should
be directed by a common vision or purpose. They assert, “It should be apparent
that schools have no immutable or transcendent purpose. … What they are
supposed to be doing depends on who controls them and what these controllers
want them to do”. The Thompson proposal for Wisconsin’s schools embraces
this belief system it is a denial of the fundamental role of public education
in affirming the public good.
A second issue which remains unexamined
in the rush to the marketplace concerns the claims offered in defense of
private school choice. Choice is offered as a “lesson learned” rather than
a proposition to be examined. Advocates of private school choice have ignored
its history. Despite the claims made for a market-based school restructuring
strategy, the history of choice does not support the claims of its proponents.
A Declaration of Crisis
Willingness to abandon strong support
for public schools and to turn to marketplace solutions is driven by a
crisis rhetoric. This rhetoric, which suggests that public education is
failing, is not only misleading, it is dangerous because it may erode public
confidence in the very institutions on which our capacity for a democratic
response depends.
Criticism of public education has continued
unabated since the publication of A Nation At Risk in 1983. Stimulated
in large part by new international economic realities, by a domestic economy
based on traditional production models, and by changing domestic demographics,
the critics have sought solutions to these challenging problems by turning
to schools and educators. The data cited by critics of public schools were
accepted at face value until the late 1980’s. However, since then, a variety
of research reports have revealed that much of the criticism has been simplistic
and has distorted and misrepresented the conditions of public education.
The credibility of the crisis-in-education
claim, in fact, rests not on immutable evidence of school failure but,
rather, on a linkage which has been established by critics between education
and other social problems such as violent crime, drug use, family instability,
and economic uncertainty. Although schools are not charged directly with
creating these problems, the public is turning to public education for
solutions to broad and complex social conditions. This occurred in the
1950’s in response to the Russian scientific and military challenge, in
the 1960’s in response to the challenge of racial segregation, and again
in the 1980’s in response to the challenges of international economic competition
and changing social circumstances.
Economic interests have emerged during
the last decade as vocal and persistent advocates of school change. These
critics have framed the issue in terms of economic competitiveness, job
creation, profit, and preparation for the work place. The purpose of public
education has been redefined by economic interests so as to put schools
in the service of capitalism rather than democracy. They are not the same.
This dramatic reframing of educational purpose has gone relatively unchallenged
in the dialogue about school improvement.
What does it mean to put schools in the
service of an economic philosophy rather than in the service of democracy,
a political and social philosophy? To define students as merely economic
beings is to deny them their basic and essential humanity and is to render
our political freedom subservient to the interests of those whose purpose
is profit. What, then, is the role of the school in a political democracy
where, for the moment, the dominant economic interests remain consolidated
in large corporate structures? The answer is to be found in an examination
of what it means to educate for the public good.
The Public Good
The growing public sentiment that government
has failed and is doomed to fail when it attempts to develop collective
solutions to broad social problems is a measure of the success of economic
interests over the past fifteen years in redefining the public good. Public
good is increasingly defined and measured by the extent to which private
interests are allowed to extend the reach of the marketplace. Although
choice, as a general principle, is worth protecting, “its effectiveness
in addressing social problems depends on its being used in the context
of confident and legitimate government authority, not as an alternative
to such authority”.
Lost in the crisis quality of the debate
about private school choice is an understanding that public schools are
not merely service providers. Public schools are not merely places where
the individual’s or the society’s economic needs are met. Public schools
have a special status as producers of values, perspectives, knowledge,
and skills which are fundamental to community.
Historically, this public function was
widely celebrated. More recently, with the emergence of marketplace and
consumer analogies, individual customer satisfaction, rather than the public
good, has become a primary consideration.
Individualism, the promise of individual
freedom and personal happiness, has been a central tenet of the American
dream and is fundamental in American society. The danger we face is that
individualism, as exemplified by private school choice, may further isolate
Americans from each other and undermine the conditions of freedom. Kelly
summarizes this sentiment:
“Hopes for short-term gains have largely
eclipsed any sense of long-range national goals or principles. It is thus
small wonder no one can agree on how to ‘fix’ systems of public education
- which by their very nature are future oriented”.
The question, ‘Education for what?’ crystallizes
the issue of public good. A fundamental tension exists between two polarities.
On the one hand, education for democracy views education as fundamental,
with the responsibility of transmitting values and skills which sustain
democracy. In a democracy citizens play two roles: as informed, intelligent
arbiters of issues and as protectors of values. While a democracy may be
viewed as an open forum of values, not all values are equal. A few are
central: respect for minority opinions, freedom of expression, and allegiance
to reason over unreason.
On the other hand, education for economic
interest views education as a dependent variable. In this view, education’s
success is judged by whether it satisfies marketplace needs thus, the marketplace
determines the nature of schooling. Economic interests are narrowly personalized
with little commitment to the collective or broad public good. The question,
Does education work? is answered only in terms of personal, family or corporate
economic success.
This tension, between an America where
individuals are perceived as creating the good economic life for themselves
and an America where citizens possess the right and duty of self governance,
not as individuals, but as a community, is at the heart of the debate about
private school choice. At its core, the debate is about the extent to which
knowledge or access to knowledge is privileged. The effects of privilege
are most apparent in the disparities of resources available to wealthy
and poor school districts which Jonathan Kozol has documented in striking
fashion in his book, “Savage Inequalities.”
The issue is quite simple: Who in a democracy
has the right to know what? The policy question which follows is, Will
public resources be diverted from schools whose purpose is perpetuating
the public good? The answer to this question has implications for the parents
and children involved and for the nature of our collective future.
The concept of the public good suggests
that public education is neither exclusively public nor exclusively private.
Democracy is not just an instrument for accomplishing some other policy
objective. It is a way of living together in a pluralistic and difficult
world.
Private School Choice: The Marketplace
Metaphor
Private school choice has been offered
as a marketplace solution to the perceived crisis in education. Advocates
of a marketplace solution point to efficiency and quality as a consequence
of a competitive market structure. The simple analogy between choosing
a school and shopping at the mall for a pair of tennis shoes has great
appeal to some. Yet, in purely economic terms, the market and the exercise
of choice within that market, is fraught with uncertainty. Consequently,
a laissez faire setting does not assure quality, but, rather, demands consumer
vigilance.
The alternative, consumer protection through
the imposition of standards by some regulatory agency, has been a consequence
of consumers facing unacceptable levels of risk. Advocates of private school
choice are eager to escape minimal educational standards however, by embracing
a marketplace of educational providers they also give up the assurance
of quality.
Private school choice carries no inherent
focus, value, purpose, or quality it is merely a policy tool which can
be used to address some perceived educational problem. The historical record
of school choice reveals its instrumental nature and that history suggests
that choice produces results acceptable in a democratic society only when
sustained by authoritative government action and careful supervision.
How has choice been used in the past? Following
the elimination of a dual education system by the Supreme Court in 1954,
a number of states created alternative private school systems subsidized
by public funds, as mechanisms to avoid racial integration. In some states,
tuition vouchers were used to help defray the costs of nonsectarian private
schools. The federal courts ultimately ruled that no freedom-of-choice
plan would relieve local school authorities of the responsibility to desegregate
public schools.
During the 1970s, magnet schools, as manifestations
of choice, were used to facilitate integration. Through the intervention
of the federal courts, magnet schools within the public school system became
a way to minimize forced busing and yet integrate the public schools. By
1981-82, there were over a thousand magnet schools in the United States.
In some communities, where segregated schools
continued, magnet schools were used to improve the quality of education
available to minority children. New York’s District No. 4 had created 23
choice programs by 1985. In Cambridge, Massachusetts, a controlled choice
program ended the drift toward segregation and narrowed the achievement
gap between minority and white students. In Milwaukee, private school choice
appeared not to improve the student achievement gap, although it did produce
higher levels of parental satisfaction.
The case for market-based school choice
rests on two claims: that there is evidence that choice works and that
there is an explanation for why it works. Evidence for the argument that
choice works is more mixed and uncertain than advocates have claimed. Although
the debate continues, the issue of whether choice works may not be as important
as why it appears to work in some instances in some communities. The marketplace
perspective holds that private school choice (including magnet schools)
“works” because it represents an alternative to government intervention,
control, and authority. Successful examples of choice are more appropriately
understood as having been the product of strong and authoritative government
leadership such as in Cambridge and East Harlem where public school choice
has been defined, controlled, and supported by the public. These successes
demonstrate that government controls are required to produce the promised
results. The marketplace cannot and will not secure the public good.
Conclusions
Since 1983, with the publication of A
Nation at Risk, it has been argued that the condition of public education
has put this nation at economic risk. While there is plenty of evidence
to support the claim of economic distress – declining profits, high levels
of urban unemployment, declining levels of wages and fringe benefits, a
growing international trade imbalance, a level standard of living – there
is no evidence that public schools are responsible for the conditions of
the American economy. Nevertheless, the solutions which have subsequently
emerged have been oriented to the marketplace – youth apprenticeships,
school-to-work, education for employment, tech prep, and private and public
school choice.
What has not emerged is a broad consensus
among citizens that private school choice is an appropriate and acceptable
alternative to public education. Although citizens support the concept
of public school choice, they do not support the use of public funds to
support private sectarian or nonsectarian school choice. Parents of public
school students continue to be supportive of the teachers and schools their
children attend (Elam, Rose and Gallup, 1994). This generalization erodes
in urban communities facing growing economic stress.
The concerns of parents in urban areas
are driven by the flight of large corporations from the city. The erosion
of an economic base which is fundamental to the maintenance of healthy
family and community structures has left the public schools as the most
visible remaining community institutions in urban settings. Communities,
families, and the schools that serve them simply cannot endure and thrive
in a climate of economic abandonment. Private school choice is a diversion
sponsored by those whose collective economic decisions have made life in
our urban community a daily struggle for survival.
References
Chubb, John E. and Moe, Terry M. Politics,
Markets, and America’s Schools. Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution,
1990.
Elam, Stanley, M., Rose, Lowell C., and
Gallup, Alec M. “The 26th Annual Phi Delta Kappa/Gallup Poll of the Public’s
Attitudes Toward the Public Schools.” Phi Delta Kappan (September 1994):
41-56.
Henig, Jeffrey R. Rethinking School Choice:
The Limits of the Market Metaphor. Princeton:Princeton University Press,
1994.
Kelly, Elizabeth A. Education, Democracy,
and Public Knowledge. Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1995.
Kozol, Jonathan. Savage Inequalities. New
York: Crown Press, 1991.
Plank, David N. and Boyd, William Lowe.
“Antipolitics, Education, and Institutional Choice: The Flight From Democracy.”
American Educational Research Journal (Summer 1994): 263-281.
Witte, John. Third Year Report: Milwaukee
Parental Choice Program. Madison, WI: Robert La Follette Institute of Public
Affairs, 1993.